[p2p-research] The new triarchy: the commons, enterprise, the state
Michel Bauwens
michelsub2004 at gmail.com
Tue Aug 24 17:48:07 CEST 2010
The new triarchy: the commons, enterprise, the state
soon on the blog:
At the P2P Foundation, our central concept is peer to peer, i.e. the ability
to freely associate with others around the creation of common value. More
specifically, we call this, according to the structural anthropology of Alan
Page Fiske, communal shareholding, i.e. the non-reciprocal exchange of an
individual with a totality. It is totality that we call the commons.
Commons can be subdivided in different ways, for example,
local-regional-global, but also between the polarity of rivalry and
non-rivalry. Commons consisting of rival goods can be renewable or not, but
in each case, there have to be rules regulating the exchange between the
commons and its users/contributors/members. In digital commons, though they
are dependent on a rival physical infrastructure in order to exist, non- or
anti-rivalry prevails, and non-reciprocal exchange is non-problematic.
It is customary to divide society into three sectors, and what we want to
show is how the new peer to peer dynamic unleashed by networked
infrastructures, changes the inter-relationship between these three sectors.
In the current ‘cognitive capitalist’ system, it is the private sector
consisting of enterprises and businesses which is the primary factor, and it
is engaged in competitive capital accumulation. The state is entrusted with
the protection of this process. Though civil society, through the citizen,
is in theory ‘sovereign’, and chooses the state; in practice, both civil
society and the state are under the domination of the private sector.
Of course, this is not to say that the state is a mere tool of private
business. In my view, it fulfills three contradictory functions. One is the
protect the whole system, under the domination of private business, and this
is determined by a balance of power not only between different private
business sectors, but also by the social balance of power between business
and civil society, capital and labour. It is only when this balance of power
is severely disturbed, that the state either becomes a private tool of some
dominant business clique, or, can become relatively independent, as in the
case of the fascist state.
So, to the first function of being the protector of the total system under
domination of capital, we should add two added functions. It is the
protector of civil society, depending on the balance of power and
achievements of social movements. And finally it is also the protector of
its own independent interests.
We have historically seen three scenarios in the 20th century. Under
fascism, the state achieves great independence from the private sector ,
which may become subservient to the state. Under the welfare state, the
state becomes a protector of the social balance of power and manages the
achievements of the social movement; and finally, under the neoliberal
corporate welfare state, or ‘market state’, it serves most directly the
interests of the financial sector.
Each sector also had its key institutions and forms of property.
The state managed a public sector, under its own property.
The private sector , under a regime of private ownership, is geared to
profit, discounts social and natural externalities, both positive and
negative, and uses its dominance in society to use and dominate the state.
Civil society has a certain power through the mechanisms of civil society,
but the great majority of its members are in a disadvantaged position
because it lacks ownership of the means of production.
However, civil society has a relative power as well, through its capability
of creating social movements and associations. Amongst those are religious
institutions, civil associations, political parties, the labour movement,
identity and sectoral movements, and since the 1960’s mostly, issue-oriented
non-profits. In the context of industrial and cognitive capitalism, natural
resource commons slowly disappeared, and the institution of the commons
became a non-player, in the dual struggle between the private and the state
sector, influenced by the relative strength or weakness of civil society and
its movements.
Capitalism has historically been a pendulum between the private and the
public sector, and the commons mostly irrelevant in the struggles for more
or less state intervention.
However, this configuration is changing, in my opinion due to two factors. The
first is the environmental crisis, i.e. the endangerment of the biosphere
through the workings of ‘selfish’ market players; the second is the role of
the new digital commons.
The first factor is of course the continuing damage done to the biosphere,
through pollution, resource depletion, endangered biodiversity, climate
change, and similar issues. It is becoming increasingly clear that
capitalist enterprise, whose DNA makes it incapable to care about
externalities, and the infinite growth engine of which it is a part, are
endangering the planet. At the same time, the idea of state-owned economies
and centralized planning has lots its luster as an alternative. This leads
to a revival of the idea of natural resource commons, since studies have
cited by Ostrom have shown that no working commons has ever degraded its
environment.
The second factor is the emergence of the digital commons. It is the
experience of creating knowledge, culture, software and design commons, by a
combination of voluntary contributions, entrepreneurial coalitions and
infrastructure-protecting for-benefit associations, that has most tangibly
re-introduced the idea of commons, for all to use without discrimination,
and where all can contribute. It has drastically reduced the production,
distribution, transaction and coordination costs for the immaterial value
that is at the core also of all what we produce physically, since that needs
to be made, needs to be designed. It has re-introduced communing as a
mainstream experience for at least one billion internet users, and has come
with proven benefits and robustness that has outcompeted and outcooperated
its private rivals. It also of course offers new ways to re-imagine, create
and protect physical commons.
The combined failure of state fundamentalism in 1989 and so-called ‘free
market’ ideology in 2008, coupled with the emergence of the peer to peer
practices and the commons, has put this alternative back on the agenda.
Peer production gives us an advance picture of how a commons-oriented
society would look like. At its core is a commons and a community
contributing to it, either voluntarily, or as paid entrepreneurial
employees. It does this through collaborative platforms using open
standards. Around the commons emerges enterprises that create added value to
operate on the marketplace, but also help the maintenance and the expansion
of the commons they rely on. A third partner are the for-benefit
associations that maintain the infrastructure of cooperation. Public
authorities could play a role if they wanted to support existing commons or
the creation of new commons, for the value they bring to society.
Non- or anti-rival commons do not need to worry about the depletion of their
stocks, so no trusts are necessary, but they use peer property modalities
such as special licenses, which insure the common stock cannot be
privatized, and that those that use the commons and improve on it, also
improve the commons at the same time.
But commons of rival or depletable goods need a trust.
Generally speaking, if a commons is not created as in the case of the
digital commons, it is something that is inherited from nature or former
generations, given in trust and usufruct, so that it can be transmitted to
our descendents. The proper institution for such commons is therefore the
trust, which is a corporate form that cannot touch its principal capital,
but has to maintain it.
So here we have it, the new triarchy:
- The state, with its public property and representative mechanisms
of governance (in the best scenario)
- The private sector, with the corporation and private property
- The commons, with the Trust (or the for-benefit association), and
which is the ‘property’ of all its members (not the right word in the
context of the commons, since it has a different philosophy of ownership)
The emergence of peer to peer dynamics and the commons does not of course
mean that society will change radically from the outset. I believe some
different phases can be contemplated.
In a first phase, the commons simply emerges as an added alternative. But as
it proves it worth and creates the accompanying social movements that
create, defend and expand it, it starts becoming a subsector of society, and
starts influencing the whole. Eventually, it reaches a phase where society
needs to be reformed (let’s call this the parity level). However, it is not
realistic that the state form that was created to protect a given class
structure, can also serve for a new structure, and therefore at some point,
phase transition and transformation will need to occur.
Let us now imagine how a commons-dominated, i.e. after the phase transition,
society would look like.
- At its core would be a collection of commons, represented by
trusts and for-benefit associations, which protect their common assets for
the benefit of present and future generations
- The commons ‘rents out’ the use of its resources to
entrepreneurs. In other words, business still exists, though infinite
growth-based capitalism does not. However, it is unlikely that traditional
corporations, wo do not take into account externalities, will still exist
without modification. More likely is that the corporate forms will be
influenced by the commons and that profit will be subsumed to other goals,
that are congruent with the maintenance of the commons. Also likely, these
entities will be owned by the producers, and not by abstract capital (we’re
talking after the phase transition here)
- The state will still exist, but will have a radically different
nature. Much of its functions will have been taken over by commons
institutions, but since these institutions care primarily about their
commons, and not the general common good, we will still need public
authorities that are the guarantor of the system as a whole, and can
regulate the various commons, and protect the commoners against possible
abuses. So in our scenario, the state does not disappear, but is
transformed, though it may greatly diminish in scope, and with its remaining
functions thoroughly democratized and based on citizen participation.
In our vision, it is civil-society based peer production, through the
Commons, which is the guarantor of value creation by the private sector, and
the role of the state, as Partner State, is to enable and empower the
creation of common value. The new peer to peer state then, though some may
see that as a contradictio in terminis, is a state which is subsumed under
the Commons, just as it is now under the private sector. Such a peer to peer
state, if we are correct, will have a much more modest role than the state
under a classic state society, with many of its functions taken over by
civil society associations, interlinked in processes of global governance.
The above then, this triarchy, is the institutional core which replaces the
dual private-public binary system that is characteristic of the capitalist
system that is presently the dominant format.
--
P2P Foundation: http://p2pfoundation.net - http://blog.p2pfoundation.net
Connect: http://p2pfoundation.ning.com; Discuss:
http://listcultures.org/mailman/listinfo/p2presearch_listcultures.org
Updates: http://del.icio.us/mbauwens; http://friendfeed.com/mbauwens;
http://twitter.com/mbauwens; http://www.facebook.com/mbauwens
Think tank: http://www.asianforesightinstitute.org/index.php/eng/The-AFI
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://listcultures.org/pipermail/p2presearch_listcultures.org/attachments/20100824/a781039f/attachment.html>
More information about the p2presearch
mailing list