[p2p-research] Mervyn King on the (non-)future of central banks
Martien van Steenbergen
Martien at AardRock.COM
Wed May 27 16:23:39 CEST 2009
A plea for a fully digital giral distributed monetary infrastructure.
As promised a copy of the 1999 speech of Mervyn King, Governor of the
bank of England on:
The future of central banks
Despite some ups and downs, central banks are ending this century well
ahead of where they started it. There are more of them, and they have
greater power and influence. But is this the peak? Will future
historians look back on central banks as a phenomenon largely of the
twentieth century? Although central banks have matured, they not yet
reached old age. There remains much to be done.
The case for price stability, and the role of central bank
independence in achieving it, needs to be made to a wide audience. We
must build a constituency for low inflation, without having to resort
to episodes of high inflation to prove that instability is costly. To
that end, communication has become more important – central banks have
moved from mystery and mystique to transparency and openness. The
language of central banking must evolve to reflect the need to
maintain broader support for the objective of stability and the
legitimacy of independent central banks in pursuing it.
Looking further ahead, the future of central banks is not entirely
secure. Their numbers may decline over the next century. The
enthusiasm of governments for national currencies has waned as capital
flows have become liberalised and exchange rates more volatile.
Following the example of the European Central Bank, more regional
monetary unions could emerge. Short of this, the creation of currency
boards, or even complete currency substitution, might also reduce the
number of independent national monetary authorities.
But much more important is the potential impact of technological
innovation. At present, central banks are the monopoly supplier of
base money – cash and bank reserves. Because base money is the
ultimate medium of exchange and of final settlement, central banks
have enormous leverage over the value of transactions in the economy,
even though the size of their balance sheet is very small in relation
to those of the private sector.
For years, economists have had difficulty in incorporating money into
rigorous general equilibrium models. To the elegance of the Walrasian
model of an exchange economy has been bolted on an assumption about
the technology of making payments such as a “cash in advance”
constraint. These untidy ways of introducing money into economic
models are not robust to changes in institutions and technology. Is it
possible that advances in technology will mean that the arbitrary
assumptions necessary to introduce money into rigorous theoretical
models will become redundant, and that the world may come to resemble
a pure exchange economy?
Electronic transactions in real time hold out that possibility. There
is no reason, in principle, why final settlements could not be carried
out by the private sector without the need for clearing through the
central bank. The practical implementation of such a system would
require much greater computing power than is at present available. But
there is no conceptual obstacle to the idea that two individuals
engaged in a transaction could settle by a transfer of wealth from one
electronic account to another in real time.
Pre-agreed algorithms would determine which financial assets were sold
by the purchaser of the good or service according to the value of the
transaction. And the supplier of that good or service would know that
incoming funds would be allocated to the appropriate combination of
assets as prescribed by another pre-agreed algorithm. Eligible assets
would be any financial assets for which there were market-clearing
prices in real time. The same system could match demands and supplies
of financial assets, determine prices and make settlements.
Financial assets and real goods and services would be priced in terms
of a unit of account. The choice of a unit of account (perhaps a
commodity standard, which would produce broad stability in the price
level) would be a matter for public choice and regulation, along the
lines of existing weights and measures inspectors. Final settlement
could be made without any recourse to the central bank. As Henckel et
al. (1999) have noted, the key to a central bank’s ability to
implement monetary policy is that it “remains, by law or regulation,
the only entity which is allowed to ‘corner’ the market for settlement
balances”.
Without such a role in settlements, central banks, in their present
form, would no longer exist; nor would money. Economies of this kind
have been discussed by Black (1970), Fama (1980) and Hall (1983). The
need to limit excessive money creation would be replaced by a concern
to ensure the integrity of the computer systems used for settlement
purposes. A regulatory body to monitor such systems would be required.
Existing regulators, including central banks, would no doubt compete
for that responsibility. Moreover, in just the same way as the
Internet is unaware of national boundaries, settlement facilities
would become international.
The key to any such developments is the ability of computers to
communicate in real time to permit instantaneous verification of the
credit worthiness of counterparties, thereby enabling private sector
real time gross settlement to occur with finality. Any securities for
which electronic markets exist could be used as part of the settlement
process. There would be no unique role for base money, and hence the
central bank monopoly of base money issue would have no value. Central
banks would lose their ability to implement monetary policy. The
successors to Bill Gates would have put the successors to Alan
Greenspan out of business.
As a central banker interested in information technology, should I
regard this prospect as a dream or a nightmare? Perhaps the answer is
that central bankers should enjoy life today. I shall place my faith
in the words of Walter Bagehot who, in Lombard Street (1873), wrote
that “Nothing would persuade the English people to abolish the Bank of
England; and if some calamity swept it away, generations must elapse
before at all the same trust would be placed in any other equivalent.”
Central banks may be at the peak of their power. There may well be
fewer central banks in the future, and their extinction cannot be
ruled out. Societies have managed without central banks in the past.
They may well do so again in the future. The website of my favourite
football team has the banner “heroes and villains”. For some, central
bankers are heroes – more powerful and responsible than political
leaders – and for others they are villains – too fanatical to be
entrusted with the world economy. For all our sakes, it is important
that central bankers are seen neither as heroes nor villains. They
should be modest technicians, striving to improve the way they use the
tools of their trade, and always eager to learn. Openness of mind and
fleetness of foot will be the best way to avoid extinction.
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: <http://listcultures.org/pipermail/p2presearch_listcultures.org/attachments/20090527/4636dff8/attachment.html>
More information about the p2presearch
mailing list