Return-Path: Received: from smtp4.osuosl.org (smtp4.osuosl.org [IPv6:2605:bc80:3010::137]) by lists.linuxfoundation.org (Postfix) with ESMTP id 83E65C0012 for ; Tue, 7 Dec 2021 17:24:49 +0000 (UTC) Received: from localhost (localhost [127.0.0.1]) by smtp4.osuosl.org (Postfix) with ESMTP id 710F341C36 for ; Tue, 7 Dec 2021 17:24:49 +0000 (UTC) X-Virus-Scanned: amavisd-new at osuosl.org X-Spam-Flag: NO X-Spam-Score: -2.098 X-Spam-Level: X-Spam-Status: No, score=-2.098 tagged_above=-999 required=5 tests=[BAYES_00=-1.9, DKIM_SIGNED=0.1, DKIM_VALID=-0.1, DKIM_VALID_AU=-0.1, DKIM_VALID_EF=-0.1, FREEMAIL_FROM=0.001, HTML_MESSAGE=0.001, RCVD_IN_DNSWL_NONE=-0.0001, SPF_HELO_NONE=0.001, SPF_PASS=-0.001] autolearn=ham autolearn_force=no Authentication-Results: smtp4.osuosl.org (amavisd-new); dkim=pass (2048-bit key) header.d=gmail.com Received: from smtp4.osuosl.org ([127.0.0.1]) by localhost (smtp4.osuosl.org [127.0.0.1]) (amavisd-new, port 10024) with ESMTP id GyrFgvvev-kF for ; Tue, 7 Dec 2021 17:24:45 +0000 (UTC) X-Greylist: whitelisted by SQLgrey-1.8.0 Received: from mail-yb1-xb2e.google.com (mail-yb1-xb2e.google.com [IPv6:2607:f8b0:4864:20::b2e]) by smtp4.osuosl.org (Postfix) with ESMTPS id 9248A41C27 for ; Tue, 7 Dec 2021 17:24:45 +0000 (UTC) Received: by mail-yb1-xb2e.google.com with SMTP id q74so42708068ybq.11 for ; Tue, 07 Dec 2021 09:24:45 -0800 (PST) DKIM-Signature: v=1; a=rsa-sha256; c=relaxed/relaxed; d=gmail.com; s=20210112; h=mime-version:references:in-reply-to:from:date:message-id:subject:to :cc; bh=4vLAi0zJlS+6qvzUwcWcjr3fFC8PNHhYVT8FlvxMiTA=; b=V/6ZRvVZcZdgExr+64xcNmzd7CplJLNwy97vna9JtsYIiypMHfZKeeNUf7xfFy+IL7 isguggwbfrNzbDMEtAEYWOtK6aEp9p7qpVGSpq8QR0M5yJzYXvrJYy9nnl9NEHoTlcc3 KIaH4uPHoa/L9DAGpONjILc7Zjg5lf5aqMQgi0pujnTODQr/1iZzqLbtU572ZAoRTT51 ex85BzJZPSbaFcDCp9N5BkfQ8mLSumdLd7/qmtnuQ/ZmrmhXyaWvRZHpnMvptBeO8Q59 icvMrFjhg10CiCv2V54j5Iy+f19tUMDUIfx/rUqAjPP7+l0l08Zpp2d55MESUKxA/7yd nWpg== X-Google-DKIM-Signature: v=1; a=rsa-sha256; c=relaxed/relaxed; d=1e100.net; s=20210112; h=x-gm-message-state:mime-version:references:in-reply-to:from:date :message-id:subject:to:cc; bh=4vLAi0zJlS+6qvzUwcWcjr3fFC8PNHhYVT8FlvxMiTA=; b=mbV0pgFdqn7bKg1cjQT+KMNRS3XlBrCZKkeHh64MKdQ0pmuFp1zUkVlw2WiPPcETNM h+/aaERrGEDb6lQBMitH05IPmkAFaA0w0tmTuffWXuev2pKhmqgZscN/zKlp4M8YvX8c 67SwnUphxbyndvbvd73O+ZJt6O2GkuRUJ6puX0gBTW3WQJDefypW01tM746/9e1ODp4R K3o33WDG0K3PrJrNsE9wezhjZ8izz04uPrn3Vn33oSqZBQiqJgiQBaLfu3ULiN+X5LXK AyWaHs3J+iSJ6O/aX3TMjs71tF/hmL1dulqnQEWkA7Rw04TJI9c3L9c3Su3zrn9P+qPd R9AQ== X-Gm-Message-State: AOAM532geExtkBqCNAE+Br81XpwciEN08NpgJXiJxz6P/P/MUOwbxuIC 5syExyiyH77yoidGFJfjt2l2OrallzqOnD2Wf+U= X-Google-Smtp-Source: ABdhPJxCoa23qsYvdXWM2ztMeHRpKpeWJSv3aEb3y/sxoD0z1VgwY0PPHK4YHG9erVeiZXDKM0IysvpNTd8pW9WtOvA= X-Received: by 2002:a25:c6d7:: with SMTP id k206mr49457461ybf.756.1638897884299; Tue, 07 Dec 2021 09:24:44 -0800 (PST) MIME-Version: 1.0 References: <8wtAeG1p6qyiOWW0pIJP06_h-3ro7UTBsNO-0BMxLnSKUU6xFBMEvhyQGhjsh3gvQAjDpFajGEC0C6NSQ0Nfj8KtT1cGlaQMW_nnEkAuozM=@protonmail.com> In-Reply-To: <8wtAeG1p6qyiOWW0pIJP06_h-3ro7UTBsNO-0BMxLnSKUU6xFBMEvhyQGhjsh3gvQAjDpFajGEC0C6NSQ0Nfj8KtT1cGlaQMW_nnEkAuozM=@protonmail.com> From: Gloria Zhao Date: Tue, 7 Dec 2021 17:24:33 +0000 Message-ID: To: darosior Content-Type: multipart/alternative; boundary="00000000000037867105d291a6ed" X-Mailman-Approved-At: Tue, 07 Dec 2021 18:03:05 +0000 Cc: Bitcoin Protocol Discussion Subject: Re: [bitcoin-dev] A fee-bumping model X-BeenThere: bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org X-Mailman-Version: 2.1.15 Precedence: list List-Id: Bitcoin Protocol Discussion List-Unsubscribe: , List-Archive: List-Post: List-Help: List-Subscribe: , X-List-Received-Date: Tue, 07 Dec 2021 17:24:49 -0000 --00000000000037867105d291a6ed Content-Type: text/plain; charset="UTF-8" Content-Transfer-Encoding: quoted-printable Hi Darosior and Ariard, Thank you for your work looking into fee-bumping so thoroughly, and for sharing your results. I agree about fee-bumping's importance in contract security and feel that it's often under-prioritized. In general, what you've described in this post, to me, is strong motivation for some of the proposed changes to RBF we've been discussing. Mostly, I have some questions. > The part of Revault we are interested in for this study is the delegation process, and more > specifically the application of spending policies by network monitors (watchtowers). I'd like to better understand how fee-bumping would be used, i.e. how the watchtower model works: - Do all of the vault parties both deposit to the vault and a refill/fee to the watchtower, is there a reward the watchtower collects for a successful Cancel, or something else? (Apologies if there's a thorough explanation somewhere that I haven't already seen). - Do we expect watchtowers tracking multiple vaults to be batching multiple Cancel transaction fee-bumps? - Do we expect vault users to be using multiple watchtowers for a better trust model? If so, and we're expecting batched fee-bumps, won't those conflict? > For Revault we can afford to introduce malleability in the Cancel transaction since there is no > second-stage transaction depending on its txid. Therefore it is pre-signed with ANYONECANPAY. We > can't use ANYONECANPAY|SINGLE since it would open a pinning vector [3]. Note how we can't leverage > the carve out rule, and neither can any other more-than-two-parties contract. We've already talked about this offline, but I'd like to point out here that even transactions signed with ANYONECANPAY|ALL can be pinned by RBF unless we add an ancestor score rule. [0], [1] (numbers are inaccurate, Cancel Tx feerates wouldn't be that low, but just to illustrate what the attack would look like) [0]: https://user-images.githubusercontent.com/25183001/135104603-9e775062-5c8d-= 4d55-9bc9-6e9db92cfe6d.png [1]: https://user-images.githubusercontent.com/25183001/145044333-2f85da4a-af71-= 44a1-bc21-30c388713a0d.png > can't use ANYONECANPAY|SINGLE since it would open a pinning vector [3]. Note how we can't leverage > the carve out rule, and neither can any other more-than-two-parties contract. Well stated about CPFP carve out. I suppose the generalization is that allowing n extra ancestorcount=3D2 descendants to a transaction means it ca= n help contracts with <=3Dn+1 parties (more accurately, outputs)? I wonder if it's possible to devise a different approach for limiting ancestors/descendants, e.g. by height/width/branching factor of the family instead of count... :shrug: > You could keep a single large UTxO and peel it as you need to sponsor transactions. But this means > that you need to create a coin of a specific value according to your need at the current feerate > estimation, hope to have it confirmed in a few blocks (at least for now! [5]), and hope that the > value won't be obsolete by the time it confirmed. IIUC, a Cancel transaction can be generalized as a 1-in-1-out where the input is presigned with counterparties, SIGHASH_ANYONECANPAY. The fan-out UTXO pool approach is a clever solution. I also think this smells like a case where improving lower-level RBF rules is more appropriate than requiring applications to write workarounds and generate extra transactions. Seeing that the BIP125#2 (no new unconfirmed inputs) restriction really hurts in this case, if that rule were removed, would you be able to simply keep the 1 big UTXO per vault and cut out the exact nValue you need to fee-bump Cancel transactions? Would that feel less like "burning" for the sake of fee-bumping? > First of all, when to fee-bump? At fixed time intervals? At each block connection? It sounds like, > given a large enough timelock, you could try to greed by "trying your luck" at a lower feerate and > only re-bumping every N blocks. You would then start aggressively bumping at every block after M > blocks have passed. I'm wondering if you also considered other questions like: - Should a fee-bumping strategy be dependent upon the rate of incoming transactions? To me, it seems like the two components are (1) what's in the mempool and (2) what's going to trickle into the mempool between now and the target block. The first component is best-effort keeping incentive-compatible mempool; historical data and crystal ball look like the only options for incorporating the 2nd component. - Should the fee-bumping strategy depend on how close you are to your timelock expiry? (though this seems like a potential privacy leak, and the game theory could get weird as you mentioned). - As long as you have a good fee estimator (i.e. given a current mempool, can get an accurate feerate given a % probability of getting into target block n), is there any reason to devise a fee-bumping strategy beyond picking a time interval? It would be interesting to see stats on the spread of feerates in blocks during periods of fee fluctuation. > > In the event that you notice a consequent portion of the block is filled with transactions paying > > less than your own, you might want to start panicking and bump your transaction fees by a certain > > percentage with no consideration for your fee estimator. You might skew miners incentives in doing > > so: if you increase the fees by a factor of N, any miner with a fraction larger than 1/N of the > > network hashrate now has an incentive to censor your transaction at first to get you to panic. > Yes I think miner-harvesting attacks should be weighed carefully in the design of offchain contracts fee-bumping strategies, at least in the future when the mining reward exhausts further. Miner-harvesting (such cool naming!) is interesting, but I want to clarify the value of N - I don't think it's the factor by which you increase the fees on just your transaction. To codify: your transaction pays a fee of `f1` right now and might pay a fee of `f2` in a later block that the miner expects to mine with 1/N probability. The economically rational miner isn't incentivized if simply `f2 =3D N * f1` unless their mempool is otherwise empty. By omitting your transaction in this block, the miner can include another transaction/package paying `g1` fees instead, so they lose `f1-g1` in fees right now. In the future block, they have the choice between collecting `f2` or `g2` (from another transaction/package) in fees, so their gain is `max(f2-g2, 0)`. So the equation is more like: a miner with 1/N of the hashrate, employing this censorship strategy, gains only if `max(f2-g2, 0) > N * (f1-g1)`. More broadly, the miner only profits if `f2` is significantly higher than `g2` and `f1` is about the same feerate as everything else in your mempool: it seems like they're betting on how much you _overshoot_, not how much you bump. In general, I agree it would really suck to inadvertently create a game where miners can drive feerates up by triggering desperation-driven fee-bumping procedures. I guess this is a reason to avoid increasingly-aggressive feebumping, or strategies where we predictably overshoot. Slightly related question: in contracts, generally, the timelock deadline is revealed in the script, so the miner knows how "desperate" we are right? Is that a problem? For Revault, if your Cancel transaction is a keypath spend (I think I remember reading that somewhere?) and you don't reveal the script, they don't see your timelock deadline yes? Again, thanks for the digging and sharing. :) Best, Gloria On Tue, Nov 30, 2021 at 3:27 PM darosior via bitcoin-dev < bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org> wrote: > Hi Antoine, > > Thanks for your comment. I believe for Lightning it's simpler with regard > to the management of the UTxO pool, but harder with regard to choosing > a threat model. > Responses inline. > > > For any opened channel, ensure the confirmation of a Commitment > transaction and the children HTLC-Success/HTLC-Timeout transactions. Note= , > in the Lightning security game you have to consider (at least) 4 types of > players moves and incentives : your node, your channel counterparties, th= e > miners, the crowd of bitcoin users. The number of the last type of player= s > is unknown from your node, however it should not be forgotten you're in > competition for block space, therefore their block demands bids should be > anticipated and reacted to in consequence. With that remark in mind, > implications for your LN fee-bumping strategy will be raised afterwards. > > For a LN service provider, on-chain overpayments are bearing on your > operational costs, thus downgrading your economic competitiveness. For th= e > average LN user, overpayment might price out outside a LN non-custodial > deployment, as you don't have the minimal security budget to be on your o= wn. > > > I think this problem statement can be easily generalised to any offchain > contract. And your points stand for all of them. > "For any opened contract, ensure at any point the confirmation of a (set > of) transaction(s) in a given number of blocks" > > > Same issue with Lightning, we can be pinned today on the basis of > replace-by-fee rule 3. We can be also blinded by network mempool > partitions, a pinning counterparty can segregate all the full-nodes in a= s > many subsets by broadcasting a revoked Commitment transaction different f= or > each. For Revault, I think you can also do unlimited partitions by mutati= ng > the ANYONECANPAY-input of the Cancel. > > > Well you can already do unlimited partitions by adding different inputs t= o > it. You could malleate the witness, but since we are using Miniscript i'm > confident you would only be able in a marginal way. > > > That said, if you have a distributed towers deployment, spread across the > p2p network topology, and they can't be clustered together through > cross-layers or intra-layer heuristics, you should be able to reliably > observe such partitions. I think such distributed monitors are deployed b= y > few L1 merchants accepting 0-conf to detect naive double-spend. > > > We should aim to more than 0-conf (in)security level.. > It seems to me the only policy-level mitigation for RBF pinning around th= e > "don't decrease the abolute fees of a less-than-a-block mempool" would be > to drop the requirement on increasing absolute fees if the mempool is "fu= ll > enough" (and the feerate increases exponentially, of course). > Another approach could be by introducing new consensus rules as proposed > by Jeremy last year [0]. If we go in the realm of new consensus rules, th= en > i think that simply committing to a maximum tx size would fix pinning by > RBF rule 3. Could be in the annex, or in the unused sequence bits (althou= gh > they currently are by Lightning, meh). You could also check in the output > script that the input commits to this. > > [0] > https://lists.linuxfoundation.org/pipermail/bitcoin-dev/2020-September/01= 8168.html > > > Have we already discussed a fee-bumping "shared cache", a CPFP variation = ? > Strawman idea: Alice and Bob commit collateral inputs to a separate UTXO > from the main "offchain contract" one. This UTXO is locked by a multi-sig= . > For any Commitment transaction pre-signed, also counter-sign a CPFP with > top mempool feerate included, spending a Commitment anchor output and the > shared-cache UTXO. If the fees spike, you can re-sign a high-feerate CPF= P, > assuming interactivity. As the CPFP is counter-signed by everyone, the > outputs can be CSV-1 encumbered to prevent pinnings. If the share-cache i= s > feeded at parity, there shouldn't be an incentive to waste or maliciously > inflate the feerate. I think this solution can be easily generalized to > more than 2 counterparties by using a multi-signature scheme. Big issue, = if > the feerate is short due to fee spikes and you need to re-sign a > higher-feerate CPFP, you're trusting your counterparty to interact, thoug= h > arguably not worse than the current update fee mechanism. > > > It really looks just like `update_fee`. Except maybe with the property > that you have the channel liquidity not depend on the onchain feerate. > In any case, for Lightning i think it's a bad idea to re-introduce trust > on this side post anchor outputs. For Revault it's clearly out of the > question to introduce trust in your counterparties (why would you bother > having a fee-bumping mechanism in the first place then?). Probably the sa= me > holds for all offchain contracts. > > > > For Lightning, it'd mean keeping an equivalent amount of funds as the > sum of all your > channels balances sitting there unallocated "just in case". This is not > reasonable. > > Agree, game-theory wise, you would like to keep a full fee-bumping > reserve, ready to burn as much in fees as the contested HTLC value, as it= 's > the maximum gain of your counterparty. Though perfect equilibrium is hard > to achieve because your malicious counterparty might have an edge pushing > you to broadcast your Commitment first by witholding HTLC resolution. > > Fractional fee-bumping reserves are much more realistic to expect in the > LN network. Lower fee-bumping reserve, higher liquidity deployed, in theo= ry > higher routing fees. By observing historical feerates, average offchain > balances at risk and routing fees expected gains, you should be able to > discover an equilibrium where higher levels of reserve aren't worth the > opportunity cost. I guess this equilibrium could be your LN fee-bumping > reserve max feerate. > > Note, I think the LN approach is a bit different from what suits a custod= y > protocol like Revault, as you compute a direct return of the frozen > fee-bumping liquidity. With Revault, if you have numerous bitcoins > protected, it's might be more interesting to adopt a "buy the mempool, > stupid" strategy than risking fund safety for few percentages of interest > returns. > > > True for routing nodes. For wallets (if receiving funds), it's not about > an investment: just users expectations to being able to transact without > risking to lose their funds (ie being able to enforce their contract > onchain). Although wallets they are much less at risk. > > > This is where the "anticipate the crowd of bitcoin users move" point can > be laid out. As the crowd of bitcoin users' fee-bumping reserves are > ultimately unknown from your node knowledge, you should be ready to be a > bit more conservative than the vanilla fee-bumping strategies shipped by > default. In case of massive mempool congestion, your additional > conservatism might get your time-sensitive transactions and game on the > crowd of bitcoin users. First Problem: if all offchain bitcoin software > adopt that strategy we might inflate the worst-case feerate rate at the > benefit of the miners, without holistically improving block throughput. > Second problem : your class of offchain bitcoin softwares might have > ridiculous fee-bumping reserve compared > to other classes of offchain bitcoin softwares (Revault > Lightning) and > just be priced out bydesign in case of mempool congestion. Third problem = : > as the number of offchain bitcoin applications should go up with time, yo= ur > fee-bumping reserve levels based from historical data might be always lat= e > by one "bank-run" scenario. > > > Black swan event 2.0? Just rule n=C2=B03 is inherent to any kind of fee > estimation. > > For Lightning, if you're short in fee-bumping reserves you might still do > preemptive channel closures, either cooperatively or unilaterally and get > back the off-chain liquidity to protect the more economically interesting > channels. Though again, that kind of automatic behavior might be compelli= ng > at the individual node-level, but make the mempol congestion worse > holistically. > > > Yeah so we are back to the "fractional reserve" model: you can only > enforce X% of the offchain contracts your participate in.. Actually it's > even an added assumption: that you still have operating contracts, with > honest counterparties. > > > In case of massive mempool congestion, you might try to front-run the > crowd of bitcoin users relying on block connections for fee-bumping, and > thus start your fee-bumping as soon as you observe feerate groups > fluctuations in your local mempool(s). > > > I don't think any kind of mempool-based estimate generalizes well, since > at any point the expected time before the next block is 10 minutes (and a > lot can happen in 10min). > > Also you might proceed your fee-bumping ticks on a local clock instead of > block connections in case of time-dilation or deeper eclipse attacks of > your local node. Your view of the chain might be compromised but not your > ability to broadcast transactions thanks to emergency channels (in the > non-LN sense...though in fact quid of txn wrapped in onions ?) of > communication. > > > Oh, yeah, i didn't explicit "not getting eclipsed" (or more generally > "data availability") as an assumption since it's generally one made by > participants of any offchain contract. In this case you can't even have > decent fee estimation, so you are screwed anyways. > > > Yes, stay open the question on how you enforce this block insurance > market. Reputation, which might be to avoid due to the latent > centralization effect, might be hard to stack and audit reliably for an > emergency mechanism running, hopefully, once in a halvening period. Maybe > maybe some cryptographic or economically based mechanism on slashing or > swaps could be found... > > > Unfortunately, given current mining centralisation, pools are in a very > good position to offer pretty decent SLAs around that. With a block space > insurance, you of course don't need all these convoluted fee-bumping hack= s. > I'm very concerned that large stakeholders of the "offchain contracts > ecosystem" would just go this (easier) way and further increase mining > centralisation pressure. > > I agree that a cryptography-based scheme around this type of insurance > services would be the best way out. > > > Antoine > > Le lun. 29 nov. 2021 =C3=A0 09:34, darosior via bitcoin-dev < > bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org> a =C3=A9crit : > >> Hi everyone, >> >> Fee-bumping is paramount to the security of many protocols building on >> Bitcoin, as they require the >> confirmation of a transaction (which might be presigned) before the >> expiration of a timelock at any >> point after the establishment of the contract. >> >> The part of Revault using presigned transactions (the delegation from a >> large to a smaller multisig) >> is no exception. We have been working on how to approach this for a whil= e >> now and i'd like to share >> what we have in order to open a discussion on this problem so central to >> what seem to be The Right >> Way [0] to build on Bitcoin but which has yet to be discussed in details >> (at least publicly). >> >> I'll discuss what we came up with for Revault (at least for what will be >> its first iteration) but my >> intent with posting to the mailing list is more to frame the questions t= o >> this problem we are all >> going to face rather than present the results of our study tailored to >> the Revault usecase. >> The discussion is still pretty Revault-centric (as it's the case study) >> but hopefully this can help >> future protocol designers and/or start a discussion around what >> everyone's doing for existing ones. >> >> >> ## 1. Reminder about Revault >> >> The part of Revault we are interested in for this study is the delegatio= n >> process, and more >> specifically the application of spending policies by network monitors >> (watchtowers). >> Coins are received on a large multisig. Participants of this large >> multisig create 2 [1] >> transactions. The Unvault, spending a deposit UTxO, creates an output >> paying either to the small >> multisig after a timelock or to the large multisig immediately. The >> Cancel, spending the Unvault >> output through the non-timelocked path, creates a new deposit UTxO. >> Participants regularly exchange the Cancel transaction signatures for >> each deposit, sharing the >> signatures with the watchtowers they operate. They then optionally [2] >> sign the Unvault transaction >> and share the signatures with the small multisig participants who can in >> turn use them to proceed >> with a spending. Watchtowers can enforce spending policies (say, can't >> Unvault outside of business >> hours) by having the Cancel transaction be confirmed before the >> expiration of the timelock. >> >> >> ## 2. Problem statement >> >> For any delegated vault, ensure the confirmation of a Cancel transaction >> in a configured number of >> blocks at any point. In so doing, minimize the overpayments and the UTxO >> set footprint. Overpayments >> increase the burden on the watchtower operator by increasing the require= d >> frequency of refills of the >> fee-bumping wallet, which is already the worst user experience. You are >> likely to manage a number of >> UTxOs with your number of vaults, which comes at a cost for you as well >> as everyone running a full >> node. >> >> Note that this assumes miners are economically rationale, are >> incentivized by *public* fees and that >> you have a way to propagate your fee-bumped transaction to them. We also >> don't consider the block >> space bounds. >> >> In the previous paragraph and the following text, "vault" can generally >> be replaced with "offchain >> contract". >> >> >> ## 3. With presigned transactions >> >> As you all know, the first difficulty is to get to be able to >> unilaterally enforce your contract >> onchain. That is, any participant must be able to unilaterally bump the >> fees of a transaction even >> if it was co-signed by other participants. >> >> For Revault we can afford to introduce malleability in the Cancel >> transaction since there is no >> second-stage transaction depending on its txid. Therefore it is >> pre-signed with ANYONECANPAY. We >> can't use ANYONECANPAY|SINGLE since it would open a pinning vector [3]. >> Note how we can't leverage >> the carve out rule, and neither can any other more-than-two-parties >> contract. >> This has a significant implication for the rest, as we are entirely >> burning fee-bumping UTxOs. >> >> This opens up a pinning vector, or at least a significant nuisance: any >> other party can largely >> increase the absolute fee without increasing the feerate, leveraging the >> RBF rules to prevent you >> from replacing it without paying an insane fee. And you might not see it >> in your own mempool and >> could only suppose it's happening by receiving non-full blocks or with >> transactions paying a lower >> feerate. >> Unfortunately i know of no other primitive that can be used by >> multi-party (i mean, >2) presigned >> transactions protocols for fee-bumping that aren't (more) vulnerable to >> pinning. >> >> >> ## 4. We are still betting on future feerate >> >> The problem is still missing one more constraint. "Ensuring confirmation >> at any time" involves ensuring >> confirmation at *any* feerate, which you *cannot* do. So what's the >> limit? In theory you should be ready >> to burn as much in fees as the value of the funds you want to get out of >> the contract. So... For us >> it'd mean keeping for each vault an equivalent amount of funds sitting >> there on the watchtower's hot >> wallet. For Lightning, it'd mean keeping an equivalent amount of funds a= s >> the sum of all your >> channels balances sitting there unallocated "just in case". This is not >> reasonable. >> >> So you need to keep a maximum feerate, above which you won't be able to >> ensure the enforcement of >> all your contracts onchain at the same time. We call that the "reserve >> feerate" and you can have >> different strategies for choosing it, for instance: >> - The 85th percentile over the last year of transactions feerates >> - The maximum historical feerate >> - The maximum historical feerate adjusted in dollars (makes more sense >> but introduces a (set of?) >> trusted oracle(s) in a security-critical component) >> - Picking a random high feerate (why not? It's an arbitrary assumption >> anyways) >> >> Therefore, even if we don't have to bet on the broadcast-time feerate >> market at signing time anymore >> (since we can unilaterally bump), we still need some kind of prediction >> in preparation of making >> funds available to bump the fees at broadcast time. >> Apart from judging that 500sat/vb is probably more reasonable than >> 10sat/vbyte, this unfortunately >> sounds pretty much crystal-ball-driven. >> >> We currently use the maximum of the 95th percentiles over 90-days window= s >> over historical block chain >> feerates. [4] >> >> >> ## 5. How much funds does my watchtower need? >> >> That's what we call the "reserve". Depending on your reserve feerate >> strategy it might vary over >> time. This is easier to reason about with a per-contract reserve. For >> Revault it's pretty >> straightforward since the Cancel transaction size is static: >> `reserve_feerate * cancel_size`. For >> other protocols with dynamic transaction sizes (or even packages of >> transactions) it's less so. For >> your Lightning channel you would probably take the maximum size of your >> commitment transaction >> according to your HTLC exposure settings + the size of as many >> `htlc_success` transaction? >> >> Then you either have your software or your user guesstimate how many >> offchain contracts the >> watchtower will have to watch, time that by the per-contract reserve and >> refill this amount (plus >> some slack in practice). Once again, a UX tradeoff (not even mentioning >> the guesstimation UX): >> overestimating leads to too many unallocated funds sitting on a hot >> wallet, underestimating means >> (at best) inability to participate in new contracts or being "at risk" >> (not being able to enforce >> all your contracts onchain at your reserve feerate) before a new refill. >> >> For vaults you likely have large-value UTxOs and small transactions (the >> Cancel is one-in one-out in >> Revault). For some other applications with large transactions and >> lower-value UTxOs on average it's >> likely that only part of the offchain contracts might be enforceable at = a >> reasonable feerate. Is it >> reasonable? >> >> >> ## 6. UTxO pool layout >> >> Now that you somehow managed to settle on a refill amount, how are you >> going to use these funds? >> Also, you'll need to manage your pool across time (consolidating small >> coins, and probably fanning >> out large ones). >> >> You could keep a single large UTxO and peel it as you need to sponsor >> transactions. But this means >> that you need to create a coin of a specific value according to your nee= d >> at the current feerate >> estimation, hope to have it confirmed in a few blocks (at least for now! >> [5]), and hope that the >> value won't be obsolete by the time it confirmed. Also, you'd have to do >> that for any number of >> Cancel, chaining feebump coin creation transactions off the change of th= e >> previous ones or replacing >> them with more outputs. Both seem to become really un-manageable (and >> expensive) in many edge-cases, >> shortening the time you have to confirm the actual Cancel transaction an= d >> creating uncertainty about >> the reserve (how much is my just-in-time fanout going to cost me in fees >> that i need to refill in >> advance on my watchtower wallet?). >> This is less of a concern for protocols using CPFP to sponsor >> transactions, but they rely on a >> policy rule specific to 2-parties contracts. >> >> Therefore for Revault we fan-out the coins per-vault in advance. We do s= o >> at refill time so the >> refiller can give an excess to pay for the fees of the fanout transactio= n >> (which is reasonable since >> it will occur just after the refilling transaction confirms). When the >> watchtower is asked to watch >> for a new delegated vault it will allocate coins from the pool of >> fanned-out UTxOs to it (failing >> that, it would refuse the delegation). >> What is a good distribution of UTxOs amounts per vault? We want to >> minimize the number of coins, >> still have coins small enough to not overpay (remember, we can't have >> change) and be able to bump a >> Cancel up to the reserve feerate using these coins. The two latter >> constraints are directly in >> contradiction as the minimal value of a coin usable at the reserve >> feerate (paying for its own input >> fee + bumping the feerate by, say, 5sat/vb) is already pretty high. >> Therefore we decided to go with >> two distributions per vault. The "reserve distribution" alone ensures >> that we can bump up to the >> reserve feerate and is usable for high feerates. The "bonus distribution= " >> is not, but contains >> smaller coins useful to prevent overpayments during low and medium fee >> periods (which is most of the >> time). >> Both distributions are based on a basic geometric suite [6]. Each value >> is half the previous one. >> This exponentially decreases the value, limiting the number of coins. Bu= t >> this also allows for >> pretty small coins to exist and each coin's value is equal to the sum of >> the smaller coins, >> or smaller by at most the value of the smallest coin. Therefore bounding >> the maximum overpayment to >> the smallest coin's value [7]. >> >> For the management of the UTxO pool across time we merged the >> consolidation with the fanout. When >> fanning out a refilled UTxO, we scan the pool for coins that need to be >> consolidated according to a >> heuristic. An instance of a heuristic is "the coin isn't allocated and >> would not have been able to >> increase the fee at the median feerate over the past 90 days of blocks". >> We had this assumption that feerate would tend to go up with time and >> therefore discarded having to >> split some UTxOs from the pool. We however overlooked that a large >> increase in the exchange price of >> BTC as we've seen during the past year could invalidate this assumption >> and that should arguably be >> reconsidered. >> >> >> ## 7. Bumping and re-bumping >> >> First of all, when to fee-bump? At fixed time intervals? At each block >> connection? It sounds like, >> given a large enough timelock, you could try to greed by "trying your >> luck" at a lower feerate and >> only re-bumping every N blocks. You would then start aggressively bumpin= g >> at every block after M >> blocks have passed. But that's actually a bet (in disguised?) that the >> next block feerate in M blocks >> will be lower than the current one. In the absence of any predictive >> model it is more reasonable to >> just start being aggressive immediately. >> You probably want to base your estimates on `estimatesmartfee` and as a >> consequence you would re-bump >> (if needed )after each block connection, when your estimates get updated >> and you notice your >> transaction was not included in the block. >> >> In the event that you notice a consequent portion of the block is filled >> with transactions paying >> less than your own, you might want to start panicking and bump your >> transaction fees by a certain >> percentage with no consideration for your fee estimator. You might skew >> miners incentives in doing >> so: if you increase the fees by a factor of N, any miner with a fraction >> larger than 1/N of the >> network hashrate now has an incentive to censor your transaction at firs= t >> to get you to panic. Also >> note this can happen if you want to pay the absolute fees for the >> 'pinning' attack mentioned in >> section #2, and that might actually incentivize miners to perform it >> themselves.. >> >> The gist is that the most effective way to bump and rebump (RBF the >> Cancel tx) seems to just be to >> consider the `estimatesmartfee 2 CONSERVATIVE` feerate at every block >> your tx isn't included in, and >> to RBF it if the feerate is higher. >> In addition, we fallback to a block chain based estimation when estimate= s >> aren't available (eg if >> the user stopped their WT for say a hour and we come back up): we use th= e >> 85th percentile over the >> feerates in the last 6 blocks. Sure, miners can try to have an influence >> on that by stuffing their >> blocks with large fee self-paying transactions, but they would need to: >> 1. Be sure to catch a significant portion of the 6 blocks (at least 2, >> actually) >> 2. Give up on 25% of the highest fee-paying transactions (assuming they >> got the 6 blocks, it's >> proportionally larger and incertain as they get less of them) >> 3. Hope that our estimator will fail and we need to fall back to the >> chain-based estimation >> >> >> ## 8. Our study >> >> We essentially replayed the historical data with different deployment >> configurations (number of >> participants and timelock) and probability of an event occurring (event >> being say an Unvault, an >> invalid Unvault, a new delegation, ..). We then observed different >> metrics such as the time at risk >> (when we can't enforce all our contracts at the reserve feerate at the >> same time), or the >> operational cost. >> We got the historical fee estimates data from Statoshi [9], Txstats [10] >> and the historical chain >> data from Riccardo Casatta's `blocks_iterator` [11]. Thanks! >> >> The (research-quality..) code can be found at >> https://github.com/revault/research under the section >> "Fee bumping". Again it's very Revault specific, but at least the data >> can probably be reused for >> studying other protocols. >> >> >> ## 9. Insurances >> >> Of course, given it's all hacks and workarounds and there is no good >> answer to "what is a reasonable >> feerate up to which we need to make contracts enforceable onchain?", >> there is definitely room for an >> insurance market. But this enters the realm of opinions. Although i do >> have some (having discussed >> this topic for the past years with different people), i would like to >> keep this post focused on the >> technical aspects of this problem. >> >> >> >> [0] As far as i can tell, having offchain contracts be enforceable >> onchain by confirming a >> transaction before the expiration of a timelock is a widely agreed-upon >> approach. And i don't think >> we can opt for any other fundamentally different one, as you want to kno= w >> you can claim back your >> coins from a contract after a deadline before taking part in it. >> >> [1] The Real Revault (tm) involves more transactions, but for the sake o= f >> conciseness i only >> detailed a minimum instance of the problem. >> >> [2] Only presigning part of the Unvault transactions allows to only >> delegate part of the coins, >> which can be abstracted as "delegate x% of your stash" in the user >> interface. >> >> [3] >> https://lists.linuxfoundation.org/pipermail/bitcoin-dev/2020-May/017835.= html >> >> [4] >> https://github.com/revault/research/blob/1df953813708287c32a15e771ba7495= 7ec44f354/feebumping/model/statemachine.py#L323-L329 >> >> [5] https://github.com/bitcoin/bitcoin/pull/23121 >> >> [6] >> https://github.com/revault/research/blob/1df953813708287c32a15e771ba7495= 7ec44f354/feebumping/model/statemachine.py#L494-L507 >> >> [7] Of course this assumes a combinatorial coin selection, but i believe >> it's ok given we limit the >> number of coins beforehand. >> >> [8] Although there is the argument to outbid a censorship, anyone >> censoring you isn't necessarily a >> miner. >> >> [9] https://www.statoshi.info/ >> >> [10] https://www.statoshi.info/ >> >> [11] https://github.com/RCasatta/blocks_iterator >> _______________________________________________ >> bitcoin-dev mailing list >> bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org >> https://lists.linuxfoundation.org/mailman/listinfo/bitcoin-dev >> > > _______________________________________________ > bitcoin-dev mailing list > bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org > https://lists.linuxfoundation.org/mailman/listinfo/bitcoin-dev > --00000000000037867105d291a6ed Content-Type: text/html; charset="UTF-8" Content-Transfer-Encoding: quoted-printable
Hi Darosior and Ariard,

Thank you for your work loo= king into fee-bumping so thoroughly, and for sharing your results. I agree = about fee-bumping's importance in contract security and feel that it= 9;s often under-prioritized. In general, what you've described in this = post, to me, is strong motivation for some of the proposed changes to RBF w= e've been discussing. Mostly, I have some questions.

> The pa= rt of Revault we are interested in for this study is the delegation process= , and more
> specifically the application of spending policies by net= work monitors (watchtowers).

I'd like to better understand how f= ee-bumping would be used, i.e. how the watchtower model works:
- Do all = of the vault parties both deposit to the vault and a refill/fee to the watc= htower, is there a reward the watchtower collects for a successful Cancel, = or something else? (Apologies if there's a thorough explanation somewhe= re that I haven't already seen).
- Do we expect watchtowers tracking= multiple vaults to be batching multiple Cancel transaction fee-bumps?
-= Do we expect vault users to be using multiple watchtowers for a better tru= st model? If so, and we're expecting batched fee-bumps, won't those= conflict?

> For Revault we can afford to introduce malleability = in the Cancel transaction since there is no
> second-stage transactio= n depending on its txid. Therefore it is pre-signed with ANYONECANPAY. We> can't use ANYONECANPAY|SINGLE since it would open a pinning vect= or [3]. Note how we can't leverage
> the carve out rule, and neit= her can any other more-than-two-parties contract.

We've already = talked about this offline, but I'd like to point out here that even tra= nsactions signed with ANYONECANPAY|ALL can be pinned by RBF unless we add a= n ancestor score rule. [0], [1] (numbers are inaccurate, Cancel Tx feerates= wouldn't be that low, but just to illustrate what the attack would loo= k like)

[0]: https://user-ima= ges.githubusercontent.com/25183001/135104603-9e775062-5c8d-4d55-9bc9-6e9db9= 2cfe6d.png
[1]: https://user-= images.githubusercontent.com/25183001/145044333-2f85da4a-af71-44a1-bc21-30c= 388713a0d.png

> can't use ANYONECANPAY|SI= NGLE since it would open a pinning vector [3]. Note how we can't levera= ge
> the carve out rule, and neither can any other more-than-two-part= ies contract.

Well stated about CPFP carve out. I suppo= se the generalization is that allowing n extra ancestorcount=3D2 descendant= s to a transaction means it can help contracts with <=3Dn+1 parties (mor= e accurately, outputs)? I wonder if it's possible to devise a different= approach for limiting ancestors/descendants, e.g. by height/width/branchin= g factor of the family instead of count... :shrug:

> You could ke= ep a single large UTxO and peel it as you need to sponsor transactions. But= this means
> that you need to create a coin of a specific value acco= rding to your need at the current feerate
> estimation, hope to have = it confirmed in a few blocks (at least for now! [5]), and hope that the
= > value won't be obsolete by the time it confirmed.

IIUC, a C= ancel transaction can be generalized as a 1-in-1-out where the input is pre= signed with counterparties, SIGHASH_ANYONECANPAY. The fan-out UTXO pool app= roach is a clever solution. I also think this smells like a case where impr= oving lower-level RBF rules is more appropriate than requiring applications= to write workarounds and generate extra transactions. Seeing that the BIP1= 25#2 (no new unconfirmed inputs) restriction really hurts in this case, if = that rule were removed, would you be able to simply keep the 1 big UTXO per= vault and cut out the exact nValue you need to fee-bump Cancel transaction= s? Would that feel less like "burning" for the sake of fee-bumpin= g?

> First of all, when to fee-bump? At fixed time intervals? At = each block connection? It sounds like,
> given a large enough timeloc= k, you could try to greed by "trying your luck" at a lower feerat= e and
> only re-bumping every N blocks. You would then start aggressi= vely bumping at every block after M
> blocks have passed.

I= 9;m wondering if you also considered other questions like:
- Should a fe= e-bumping strategy be dependent upon the rate of incoming transactions? To = me, it seems like the two components are (1) what's in the mempool and = (2) what's going to trickle into the mempool between now and the target= block. The first component is best-effort keeping incentive-compatible mem= pool; historical data and crystal ball look like the only options for incor= porating the 2nd component.
- Should the fee-bumping strategy depend on = how close you are to your timelock expiry? (though this seems like a potent= ial privacy leak, and the game theory could get weird as you mentioned).- As long as you have a good fee estimator (i.e. given a current mempool, = can get an accurate feerate given a % probability of getting into target bl= ock n), is there any reason to devise a fee-bumping strategy beyond picking= a time interval?

It would be interesting to see stats on the spread= of feerates in blocks during periods of fee fluctuation.

> >= In the event that you notice a consequent portion of the block is filled w= ith transactions paying
> > less than your own, you might want to = start panicking and bump your transaction fees by a certain
> > pe= rcentage with no consideration for your fee estimator. You might skew miner= s incentives in doing
> > so: if you increase the fees by a factor= of N, any miner with a fraction larger than 1/N of the
> > networ= k hashrate now has an incentive to censor your transaction at first to get = you to panic.

> Yes I think miner-harvesting attacks should be we= ighed carefully in the design of offchain contracts fee-bumping strategies,= at least in the future when the mining reward exhausts further.

Miner-harvesting (such cool naming!) is interesting, but I want to clari= fy the value of N - I don't think it's the factor by which you incr= ease the fees on just your transaction.

To codify:= your transaction pays a fee of `f1` right now and might pay a fee of `f2` = in a later block that the miner expects to mine with 1/N probability. The e= conomically rational miner isn't incentivized if simply `f2 =3D N * f1`= unless their mempool is otherwise empty.
By omitting your transaction= in this block, the miner can include another transaction/package paying `g= 1` fees instead, so they lose `f1-g1` in fees right now. In the future bloc= k, they have the choice between collecting `f2` or `g2` (from another trans= action/package) in fees, so their gain is `max(f2-g2, 0)`.
So the equati= on is more like: a miner with 1/N of the hashrate, employing this censorshi= p strategy, gains only if `max(f2-g2, 0) > N * (f1-g1)`. More broadly, t= he miner only profits if `f2` is significantly higher than `g2` and `f1` is= about the same feerate as everything else in your mempool: it seems like t= hey're betting on how much you _overshoot_, not how much you bump.
<= br>In general, I agree it would really suck to inadvertently create a game = where miners can drive feerates up by triggering desperation-driven fee-bum= ping procedures. I guess this is a reason to avoid increasingly-aggressive = feebumping, or strategies where we predictably overshoot.

Slightly r= elated question: in contracts, generally, the timelock deadline is revealed= in the script, so the miner knows how "desperate" we are right? = Is that a problem? For Revault, if your Cancel transaction is a keypath spe= nd (I think I remember reading that somewhere?) and you don't reveal th= e script, they don't see your timelock deadline yes?

Again, than= ks for the digging and sharing. :)

Best,
Gloria
On Tue, Nov 30, 20= 21 at 3:27 PM darosior via bitcoin-dev <bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org> wrot= e:
Hi Antoi= ne,

Thanks for your comment. I believe fo= r Lightning it's simpler with regard to the management of the UTxO pool= , but harder with regard to choosing
a threat model.
Responses inline.


<= blockquote type=3D"cite">
For any opened channel, ensu= re the confirmation of a Commitment transaction and the children HTLC-Succe= ss/HTLC-Timeout transactions. Note, in the Lightning security game you have= to consider (at least) 4 types of players moves and incentives : your node= , your channel counterparties, the miners, the crowd of bitcoin users. The = number of the last type of players is unknown from your node, however it sh= ould not be forgotten you're in competition for block space, therefore = their block demands bids should be anticipated and reacted to in consequenc= e. With that remark in mind, implications for your LN fee-bumping strategy = will be raised afterwards.

For a LN service pr= ovider, on-chain overpayments are bearing on your operational costs, thus d= owngrading your economic competitiveness. For the average LN user, overpaym= ent might price out outside a LN non-custodial deployment, as you don't= have the minimal security budget to be on your own.

I think this problem statement can be easil= y generalised to any offchain contract. And your points stand for all of th= em.
"For any opened contract, ensure at any point the co= nfirmation of a (set of) transaction(s) in a given number of blocks"


Same issue with Lightning, we can be pinned today on the ba= sis of replace-by-fee rule 3. We can be also blinded by network mempool par= titions, a pinning counterparty can segregate all the full-nodes=C2=A0 in a= s many subsets by broadcasting a revoked Commitment transaction different f= or each. For Revault, I think you can also do unlimited partitions by mutat= ing the ANYONECANPAY-input of the Cancel.

Well you can already do unlimited partitions by adding= different inputs to it. You could malleate the witness, but since we are u= sing Miniscript i'm confident you would only be able in a marginal way.=


That said, if you have a distributed towers deployment, s= pread across the p2p network topology, and they can't be clustered toge= ther through cross-layers or intra-layer heuristics, you should be able to = reliably observe such partitions. I think such distributed monitors are dep= loyed by few L1 merchants accepting 0-conf to detect naive double-spend.

We should aim to more t= han 0-conf (in)security level..
It seems to me the only = policy-level mitigation for RBF pinning around the "don't decrease= the abolute fees of a less-than-a-block mempool" would be to drop the= requirement on increasing absolute fees if the mempool is "full enoug= h" (and the feerate increases exponentially, of course).
Another approach could be by introducing new consensus rules as proposed b= y Jeremy last year [0]. If we go in the realm of new consensus rules, then = i think that simply committing to a maximum tx size would fix pinning by RB= F rule 3. Could be in the annex, or in the unused sequence bits (although t= hey currently are by Lightning, meh). You could also check in the output sc= ript that the input commits to this.


=

Have we= already discussed a fee-bumping "shared cache", a CPFP variation= ? Strawman idea: Alice and Bob commit collateral inputs to a separate UTXO= from the main "offchain contract" one. This UTXO is locked by a = multi-sig. For any Commitment transaction pre-signed, also counter-sign a C= PFP with top mempool feerate included, spending a Commitment anchor output = and the shared-cache UTXO. If the fees spike,=C2=A0 you can re-sign a high-= feerate CPFP, assuming interactivity. As the CPFP is counter-signed by ever= yone, the outputs can be CSV-1 encumbered to prevent pinnings. If the share= -cache is feeded at parity, there shouldn't be an incentive to waste or= maliciously inflate the feerate. I think this solution can be easily gener= alized to more than 2 counterparties by using a multi-signature scheme. Big= issue, if the feerate is short due to fee spikes and you need to re-sign a= higher-feerate CPFP, you're trusting your counterparty to interact, th= ough arguably not worse than the current update fee mechanism.

It really looks just like `update= _fee`. Except maybe with the property that you have the channel liquidity n= ot depend on the onchain feerate.
In any case, for Lightning = i think it's a bad idea to re-introduce trust on this side post anchor = outputs. For Revault it's clearly out of the question to introduce trus= t in your counterparties (why would you bother having a fee-bumping mechani= sm in the first place then?). Probably the same holds for all offchain cont= racts.


> For Lightning, it'd mean keeping an equiva= lent amount of funds as the sum of all your
channels balances= sitting there unallocated "just in case". This is not reasonable= .

Agree, game-theory wise, you would like to k= eep a full fee-bumping reserve, ready to burn as much in fees as the contes= ted HTLC value, as it's the maximum gain of your counterparty. Though p= erfect equilibrium is hard to achieve because your malicious counterparty m= ight have an edge pushing you to broadcast your Commitment first by withold= ing HTLC resolution.

Fractional fee-bumping re= serves are much more realistic to expect in the LN network. Lower fee-bumpi= ng reserve, higher liquidity deployed, in theory higher routing fees. By ob= serving historical feerates, average offchain balances at risk and routing = fees expected gains, you should be able to discover an equilibrium where hi= gher levels of reserve aren't worth the opportunity cost. I guess this= =C2=A0 equilibrium could be your LN fee-bumping reserve max feerate.

Note, I think the LN approach is a bit different fro= m what suits a custody protocol like Revault,=C2=A0 as you compute a direct= return of the frozen fee-bumping liquidity. With Revault, if you have nume= rous bitcoins protected, it's might be more interesting to adopt a &quo= t;buy the mempool, stupid" strategy than risking fund safety for few p= ercentages of interest returns.

=
True for routing nodes. For wallets (if receiving funds), it'= ;s not about an investment: just users expectations to being able to transact without risking to lose their funds (ie being able to enforce their contract onchain). Although wallets they are much less at risk.


This is where the "anticipate the crowd of bitcoin users move&qu= ot; point can be laid out. As the crowd of bitcoin users' fee-bumping r= eserves are ultimately unknown from your node knowledge, you should be read= y to be a bit more conservative than the vanilla fee-bumping strategies shi= pped by default. In case of massive mempool congestion, your additional con= servatism might get your time-sensitive transactions and game on the crowd = of bitcoin users. First Problem: if all offchain bitcoin software adopt tha= t strategy we might inflate the worst-case feerate rate at the benefit of t= he miners, without holistically improving block throughput. Second problem = : your class of offchain bitcoin softwares might have ridiculous fee-bumpin= g reserve compared
to other classes of offchain bitcoin softw= ares (Revault > Lightning) and just be priced out bydesign in case of me= mpool congestion. Third problem : as the number of offchain bitcoin applica= tions should go up with time, your fee-bumping reserve levels based from hi= storical data might be always late by one "bank-run" scenario.

Black swan event 2.0? Just rule n= =C2=B03 is inherent to any kind of fee estimation.

=
For Lightning, if you&= #39;re short in fee-bumping reserves you might still do preemptive channel = closures, either cooperatively or unilaterally and get back the off-chain l= iquidity to protect the more economically interesting channels. Though agai= n, that kind of automatic behavior might be compelling at the individual no= de-level, but make the mempol congestion worse holistically.

Yeah so we are back to the "fr= actional reserve" model: you can only enforce X% of the offchain contr= acts your participate in.. Actually it's even an added assumption: that= you still have operating contracts, with honest counterparties.
<= div>

In case of massive mempool congestion, you might try to front-run th= e crowd of bitcoin users relying on block connections for fee-bumping, and = thus start your fee-bumping as soon as you observe feerate groups fluctuati= ons in your local mempool(s).

I don't think any kind of mempool-based estimate generalizes w= ell, since at any point the expected time before the next block is 10 minut= es (and a lot can happen in 10min).

Also you might proceed your fee-bumpi= ng ticks on a local clock instead of block connections in case of time-dila= tion or deeper eclipse attacks of your local node. Your view of the chain m= ight be compromised but not your ability to broadcast transactions thanks t= o emergency channels (in the non-LN sense...though in fact quid of txn wrap= ped in onions ?) of communication.
<= br>
Oh, yeah, i didn't explicit "not getting eclipsed&qu= ot; (or more generally "data availability") as an assumption sinc= e it's generally one made by participants of any offchain contract. In = this case you can't even have decent fee estimation, so you are screwed= anyways.


Yes, stay open the question on how you enforce t= his block insurance market. Reputation, which might be to avoid due to the = latent centralization effect, might be hard to stack and audit reliably for= an emergency mechanism running, hopefully, once in a halvening period. May= be maybe some cryptographic or economically based mechanism on slashing or = swaps could be found...

Unfortunately, given current mining centralisation, pools are in a = very good position to offer pretty decent SLAs around that. With a block sp= ace insurance, you=C2=A0of course don't need all these convoluted fee-b= umping hacks.
I'm very concerned that large stakeho= lders of the "offchain contracts ecosystem" would just go this (e= asier) way and further increase mining centralisation pressure.

I agree that a cryptography-based scheme around this type= of insurance services would be the best way out.

<= div>
Antoine<= br>

L= e=C2=A0lun. 29 nov. 2021 =C3=A0=C2=A009:34, darosior via bitcoin-dev <bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org> a = =C3=A9crit=C2=A0:
https://github.com/revault/research u= nder the section
"Fee bumping". Again it's very= Revault specific, but at least the data can probably be reused for
studying other protocols.


## 9. Insurances

Of course, given it's a= ll hacks and workarounds and there is no good answer to "what is a rea= sonable
feerate up to which we need to make contracts enforce= able onchain?", there is definitely room for an
insuranc= e market. But this enters the realm of opinions. Although i do have some (h= aving discussed
this topic for the past years with different = people), i would like to keep this post focused on the
techni= cal aspects of this problem.


[0] As far as i can tell, having offchain contracts be enforce= able onchain by confirming a
transaction before the expiratio= n of a timelock is a widely agreed-upon approach. And i don't think
=
we can opt for any other fundamentally different one, as you wan= t to know you can claim back your
coins from a contract after= a deadline before taking part in it.

[1] The = Real Revault (tm) involves more transactions, but for the sake of concisene= ss i only
detailed a minimum instance of the problem.

[2] Only presigning part of the Unvault transactions = allows to only delegate part of the coins,
which can be abstr= acted as "delegate x% of your stash" in the user interface.


=



[7] Of course this assumes a combinatorial coin = selection, but i believe it's ok given we limit the
numbe= r of coins beforehand.

[8] Although there is t= he argument to outbid a censorship, anyone censoring you isn't necessar= ily a
miner.



_= ______________________________________________
bitcoin-dev ma= iling list

________________= _______________________________
bitcoin-dev mailing list
= bitcoin-dev@lists.linuxfoundation.org
https://lists.linuxfoundation.org/mail= man/listinfo/bitcoin-dev
--00000000000037867105d291a6ed--